Κυριακή 4 Μαΐου 2014

Growth and the social state in Greece: from EC membership to the present crisis



(Ομιλία στο Ολλανδικό Ινστιτούτο Αθήνας στις 10 Απριλίου 2014)

1.   Introduction

It is difficult not to connect the severity of the economic crisis in Greece with the fact that during 30 years of participation in the European Union, our country did not manage to adapt to what are or were the caracteristics of a european capitalist economy and society. The administration remained inefficient, production was lagging behind, and the social state was partial and offered unequal services, while not covering all of the working population.


In reality the entry into a European Common Market, adopting at the time the new neoliberal strategy, was a factor that reinforced the conservation of existing practices and functions, and did not encourage the reforms leading to the more typical caracteristics of the “european model”. The european institutions were not interested in transforming the greek economy and society, into what with great difficulties they were trying to adandon.

Therefore the questions are: how can we read the economic and social history of the past 30 years in Greece? Is it a number of faillures on the way to “europeanisation”, or is it the result of the way the greek model was adapted to the construction of the neoliberal Europe? How can we explain that the post-dictatorial spirit of democratisation did not lead to radical reforms of clientelist and inefficient institutions but on the contrary leed to the repetition and extension of clientelist practices?

It is striking to admit that there are three important structural caracteristics of the “greek model” that existed in the beginning of the 80’s and continue to exist until now and continue to be at the same time, recognised problems and consequences of the succesive economic strategies, including the “memoranda”. These are (a) the clientelistic practices at the core of relations between the state and the various economic interests, (b) the deficitary nature of economic relations with the rest of the world, and (3) the persistence of undeclared work and absence of workers and social rights in an important part of the labour market.

The clientelistic relations between private or specific social interests and the state, were the result of the immediate post-civil-war reconstruction period when opportunities to make money and build enterprises were almost exclusively a function of the relations with the political personel. The post war state was build to serve these type of relations, and its inefficiency was simply the other side of its capacity to adapt to the various demands of these interests.

This approach of economic develpment policy was supplemented by some important investments (in the late 50’s and the 60’s) which did not solve the serious problems concerning the general economic equilibriium – external or internal. The economic developent of the 60’s and 70’s would have been impossible without the greek migrants’s money, and the money of the greek sailors in the merchant fleet, but also without the fast developping tourist sector. Industrial production was even before the late 70’s underdeveloped from the quantitative and technological point of view, social spending also, and the salary earners protected by labour and social laws were mainly those of the public sector.

Such an economic and social model did not have something to do with the “european model”, with the social state, collective bargening and collective agreements. The military dictatorship was the result of the incapacity of the greek model to reproduce itself in the conditions of an even incomplete democracy.


2.   The contradictory 80’s

The stabilisation of the post-dictatorship regime after the 1981 elections, meant that the questions of a national economic development, of the social state and of the reform of old administrative practices were open. The PASOK government showed directly its intension to adopt a radical reformist policy concerning social and salary issues, satifsying long pending demands, and showed also its expectations about the dynamics of a keynesian strategy.

But the keynesian strategy presupposes a proper institutional framework, and most of all the ageement of the capitalist class about such a pespective, and in the precise case of Greece during that period, the agreement with a daring structural industrial policy. The creation by PASOK of an institution aiming at the reviving of “problematic” enterprises and the implementation of an industrial policy by the state met with the fierce opposition of the industrialists union.

By 1985 the PASOK government had to face the worsening balance of payments with a devaluation and an administrative reduction of salaries and wages. It was the admission of a failure to resolve through a keynesian policy the external sector problem and of the refusal of industrial capital to participate to the necessary consensus.

But bank capital was not either anxious to contribute to a remodeling of the greek economy. The reform of the administrative management of the banking system in 1987 and the “liberalisation” of the market, lead in reality to the creation of a cartel of the main banks that offered them the possibility to absorb the losses of the previous period through a common policy of high interest rates. It was the inauguration of the new financial power in Greece.

The attempt to form a “keynesian” social alliance failed and this fact had very important consequences for the form of the regime. The trade union movement of the public sector enterprises became dominant and the private sector unions were weak and in many cases defeated, after their confrontation with employers. The small and medium enterprises remained dependent to a great extent on undeclared work and tax evasion. Public sector trade unions and professional organisations established close relations with the state. The political parties maintained privileged relations with the bureaucracies of these unions and organisations. The model of relations of enterpreneurs with the state did not change and clientelistic practices remained dominant.

During the 80’s public social spending increased from 10,2% of GDP in 1980, to 16,5% in 1990 and 17% in 1993. During the same period public dept insreased from 20% of GDP to 100%. But direct taxation remained at half the average level of the European Union of 15 members. The feeling of instability and revelations of economic scandals implying the PASOK government and alllegedly the prime minister himself, led to the victory at the 1990 elections (after a right and left government and a national unity government) of the New Democracy party, lead by Constantinos Mitsotakis, who had adopted an authentic “thatcherite” program. This government resigned in 1993 after the failure of its attempt to implement privatisation of public enterprises. It had obviously underestimated the existing relations of forces in society.



3.   Stabilisation through “modernisation”

Since the end of the 80’s “modernisation” entered the political vocabulary as the most misleading though strong and lasting term. Modernisation managed to maintain the charm of “europeanisation” as understood in the past, but also to express the necesity to adapt to the changing european strategy. “Modernisation” did not come to mean anymore keynesianism and social state, but enterpreneurship and employability. Trade union bureaucracies were participating in institutions of social dialogue, but undeclared work, especially of immigrants and later the youth, was tolerated if not adopted as a strategy. The union of industrialists wellcomed the “social dialogue” institutions as long as the labour market policies were deregulating employment practices.

The success of the “modernisation” strategy was due to the fact that it was based on a solid alliance of the political leadership assuming it with the most strong and combative public sector unions. There was a “modernisation” of industrial relations in the sens of the individualisation of learning trajectories, the flexibilisation of the labour market, together with the persistence of inefficient legislation and practices concerning health and safety at the shopfloor. The attempt to renew the legislation about immigrant work waited until 1998, almost a decade after the massive entry of immigrants from the Balkans, and the responsibility to prove the existence of a work contract was left to the worker himself and not to the employer or the authorities.

“Modernisation” was also a crusade of the world of enterpreneurs against the inefficient and overdeveloped state, and the so called prejudice against private initiative. There were of course parts of the world of enterpreneurs that could not be pleased with the clientelist methods of the industrial policy, and the anti-state speech was the best way to orient discontent towards the state and away from the powerful enterprises and enterpreneurs. In the meantime the managing of the succesive Cadres Communautaires d’Appui was reproducing a typical and lasting clientelism, and reproducing also the inefficiency of the state not only concerning the relations with the individual enterpreneurs but mainly concerning the results of the sectoral economic policies. In such a context the chatter about private initiative and competitiveness could not – and did not – lead anywere, and despite the flow of european money that was reaching 4-5% of GDP per year, the greek economy was losing productive capacity and competitiveness.

While investment and growth accelerated during the second half of the 90’s, the results during the first half of the years 2000 were the fall of value added in the secondary sector from 14,5% in 2000 to 13,2% in 2004 (the lowest by far in the Union), and in the primary sector from 7,3% in 2000 to 5,6% in 2004. 2003 and 2004 were the last years with a GDP growth reaching 4,5%. But in 2004 the external commercial deficit was six times higher in value compared with the beginning of the 80’s.

Until 2004 the public debt remained at the high but stable level of 100% of GDP. The reason of this stability was that from 1993 to 2003 there was a primary surplus of public finance. The neoliberal agenda, adopted under the “modernisation” perspective, in agreement with the European Commission, contained besides the deregulation of the labour market (and the quest of cheeper work), a privatisation policy (which was until then very succesful) and a policy of reduced taxation of capital and wealth. Direct taxes increased from 1995 (6,6% of GDP) to the year 2000 (9,7% of GDP) but then fell until 2003 (7,8%) stabilising at that level. But these percentages were much lower than the EU-15 averages. Capital and wealth were taxed much less in Greece: 19,9% of their value in 2000, compared to 30,2% in the eurozone, and 16,3% in 2004, compared to 27.9% in the eurozone.

Public social expenditure had reached 19,2% of GDP in 2000 and 22,7% in 2007, before the crisis, levels compared to Portugal and Spain, and this increase was due to pensions and expenditure on health. It is obvious that social spending was “normal” but taxation of wealth was not. After the year 2000 and especially 2004, the year of the Olympic Games, the economy did not have the ressources to continue its growth and the financing of public expenditure but also consumption depended on the increase of debt, public and private. The productive private sector was continiously shrinking, and was reproducing itself through the reduction of taxes but also the deregulation of the labour market. After 2004, public debt started to increase and reached 140% of GDP in 2010.

The social alliance of the “modernisation” period between private capital, public sector trade unions and middle class professionals had lost its dynamic and its faith to a socialist party government. Factors as the privatisation and the weakening of public sector trade unions through this process, the accumulated demands of the private enterprises for cheeper labour, and reduction of social spending, the aftermath of the 1999 stock exchange crisis, were the first signs of an impasse of the economy and the end of the “modernisation” period. The continuous increase of public and private debt and the guarantee of profits through deregulation of the labour market, subsidees and taxation policy were typical bank led choices, leading directly to a crisis, and to a deep impasse of the productive private sector. The external deficit had increased, the clientelist method was a failure and the regulation through deregulation of the labour market was not sufficient. After the provisional balance of the “modernisation” period the economy was getting out of control.


4.   Conclusions

What was the force of destruction of the greek economy that we are witnessing now? It was of course the dominant forces within the private enterpeneurial sector which refused the adaptation to the entry into the european market through structural industrial policies, and fought for the persistence of their control over the state, and the reproduction of clientelist methods of state management, and also refused the complete legalisation of the labour market and the construction of a social state. Bank capital and european neoliberalism did not disagree, since “private initiative” of all sorts was the rising dogma since the 80’s.

In the present situation the choices of the troika make of course some sens in a neoliberal narrow perspective. The banks have to survive and continue to make money, and the enterpreneurial activity has to acquire some autonomous dynamic through cheep labour and adaptation to productive possibilities in the globalised economy, and all this at any social and economic cost. The troika is in fact trying to recreate a dominant social class out of practically nothing, no productive capacity, no apropriate state institutions, no perspective, and the greed of bankers, or of the big friends of politicians are not obviously sufficient.

The greek drama is the fact that no part of the elit – political or economic – is capable of taking a realistic look on society, and understand that the recent “european” hopes of the population can not be tranformed in just a few years to the despair of a suddenly marginalised working force and youth, accepting any working and living conditions. This is the reason of the extreme tensions within greek society, and the tensions within the political institutions. The european governing elite is adopting the same approach as the greek elit, punishing the people of Greece for the irresponsability and incapacity of its ruling class, accepting the destruction of social institutions and productive capacity, and offering the terrain for the reinforcement of a nazi criminal gang that is willing to fill the gap.

If the greek people are considered part of Europe, there should be at the level of the continent organised social and political forces who can support the corresponing forces in Greece, who are not only defending the democratic and social legacy of Europe, but are also aiming at the reconstruction of productive activity and society. The majority of the left is supporting the idea that the necessary reconstruction in Greece is and must be considered as a european project.



[PLR, 10-4-2014]

Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:

Δημοσίευση σχολίου